Want to read Slashdot from your mobile device? Point it at m.slashdot.org and keep reading!

 



Forgot your password?
typodupeerror
×
The Almighty Buck Businesses Databases Oracle Programming Software IT

Price Optimization Software Big in Retail Business 121

prostoalex writes "Even if you spent only a single day in an economics class, you're probably familiar with a concept of supply and demand. The Associated Press is running an article on retailers employing mathematical models for price optimization, where some products are priced higher to generate higher margins, and some are discounted to generate larger volumes even at the expense of per-product margins. DemandTec, Oracle and SAP are some of the companies producing those mathematical models for retailers around the country, with AP listing some of the pricing optimizations employed currently."
This discussion has been archived. No new comments can be posted.

Price Optimization Software Big in Retail Business

Comments Filter:
  • by tomhudson ( 43916 ) <barbara@hudson.barbara-hudson@com> on Saturday April 28, 2007 @09:22AM (#18911515) Journal

    ... after all, "price optimization" has been done for centuries, but now its "with software" instead of a paper and pencil, or a calculator, or a gut feeling.

    Seriously - this is NOT new. Not even in the software field.

    • by symbolic ( 11752 ) on Saturday April 28, 2007 @09:40AM (#18911613)
      They can optimize their little hearts out, but it won't change the fact that I counter this with my own optimization strategy- I always look for the best deal, period.
      • by AlXtreme ( 223728 ) on Saturday April 28, 2007 @09:59AM (#18911699) Homepage Journal
        So you would be willing to search for a cheaper paintbrush, taking maybe an hour of your time, even if it only saved you a dollar?

        I would also look for the best deal, but only if in doing so I'd save more per hour than I would make if I were working instead. Personally, I don't enjoy wasting my time running from store to store. Even if I'd save 50 dollars, it probably won't be worth it if that meant shopping 8 hours to find the cheapest store.

        Just my two cents.

        • by harlows_monkeys ( 106428 ) on Saturday April 28, 2007 @10:26AM (#18911855) Homepage
          What I do is default to my local Wal-Mart Supercenter (which also happens to be the 2nd nearest store, so is most convenient). On average, their prices easily beat Safeway, Albertson's, and the small regional chain store that is a little closer to me than the Wal-Mart. Furthermore, they are indeed "everyday low prices". This lets me easily memorize Wal-Mart's prices for most of my regular items.

          If I happen to be shopping at one of the other places, it is then easy to see if their current sale price beats Wal-Mart's everyday price. If so, and I need the item, or can reasonably store it, I will buy at the other store. If I notice an advertised sale on something at one of the other stores, I might go there for it.

          • The extra $15 a week I spend on groceries at Safeway is well worth the cost of not being around people who look like they want to marry their cousins, teenagers who think they're gangbangers, and 16 year old single moms. The Safeway is also cleaner and the staff friendlier.

          • How do you think WalMart prices it's products? They are not ALL cheaper than safeway or any other store (I have seen numerous examples but no I can't cite them, I just logged it away as something interesting I noticed).
          • by Anonymous McCartneyf ( 1037584 ) on Saturday April 28, 2007 @01:59PM (#18913237) Homepage Journal
            Advice for Wal*Mart shoppers:
            Never buy produce or fresh bakery goods at a Wal*Mart. The premium at the true grocery stores often corresponds to the produce & bakery goods actually being better quality.
            Also, since you actually have a choice, try to memorize the routine sale prices at your other local stores. Sales tend to be cyclical. Wal*Mart has lower prices on the most popular items; for more obscure stuff they can go higher because those items are harder to find elsewhere, or fewer people are looking for them. I learned this when trying to buy a rare iron syrup (which could've had a proof number).
            Wal*Mart is a good place to shop for low prices, but other places have different selection, and it's a good idea to give at least token support to its competition.
            • Indeed. Soda (the geek staple) for instance, is often cheaper at convenience stores and even gas stations than the supermarket or walmart.
        • He didn't say he was jumping over dollars to pickup dimes. He said he searched for the best deal; not that he searched for an hour for the best deal on piddly items. Ten minutes on the Net saved me $75 on my DVD recorder and I only had to drive to the place to pick it up less than 5 minutes away. Eight hours seems ridiculous unless you're shopping for a car or house. Hell it shouldn't take 20 minutes to call the stores in town to verify pricing.
        • by symbolic ( 11752 )
          It depends. If it's only a dollar, chances are I won't make a big deal over it. However, I've lost count of the number of times I've elected not to buy something "yet" because even after looking around, I still wasn't sure I was getting the best price. I'm sure the average consumer would go nuts with this approach, but then again, that may be why so many of them are in financial trouble, leveraged to the hilt with credit they can't afford, etc.
      • by nelsonal ( 549144 ) on Saturday April 28, 2007 @10:00AM (#18911705) Journal
        This means that you're more likely to get a sale at a price you like than without price optimization. Take for example you and your MBA gadget hungry associate. Say both of you want a LCD screen and the company's cost is $500. If they have a single mark up it might be $700, which Mr. MBA would purchase one and you none, but if they can sell to him for $800 and you for $600, both of you buy a TV and the store makes more (even though they made less in your sale it was better than no sale at the single price).
        • by njh ( 24312 )
          Which is why rebates are so effective - they separate customers into those who are money-poor/time-right who send in the coupons, and those who are money-rich/time-poor who don't bother.
        • Re: (Score:3, Informative)

          by costas ( 38724 )
          That's not price optimization: that's discriminatory pricing or price differentiation. The latter is usually done with coupons ("here's a $100 loyalty coupon for you Mr Smith"), the former is about maximizing profit (i.e. profit per unit times total units sold).

          Yes, I am a supply chain consultant...
          • I was taking price optimization to be price discrimination with a consultant approved euphemism. There are all sorts of ways to price discriminate, senior discounts, airline ticketing processes, branding, etc.
      • by no_pets ( 881013 ) on Saturday April 28, 2007 @10:11AM (#18911779)
        As someone that quit IT to go into retail I will say that price optimization will benefit retailers looking for your business more than other types of consumers.

        A specialty shop with unique products can just slap a large margin on a product as long as the price is fairly well justified and do fine, but when catering to a clientèle working with higher volumes, low margins and aggressively price conscious consumers then wringing every last possible penny out of them works.

        Everyone knows that by and large in the U.S. that Wal-Mart is the price discount king. And even if you are really watching prices and comparing a consumer will still believe that they are getting the best deal at Wal-Mart. But I know that a significant number of their products are name brands packaged into their own unique size. Of course at Sam's Club things have to be bought in bulk for a discount but comparing product X at Wal-Mart in a 13oz size verses the same product X at a local competitor in a 20oz size can appear to be the exact same product for significantly less than a competitor although the price per ounce is a better deal at the competitor.

        I sell pet food and I'll say that Ol' Roy is one of the cheapest priced pet foods per bag. Sure there are some others cheaper per bag at feed stores which may or may not be a better deal. I know some feed stores that use loss leaders to beat Ol' Roy. But, when comparing Ol' Roy to premium pet food the price per feeding will beat Ol' Roy most every time. So, buying a $15 bag of feed per week is more expensive than buying a $26 bag of feed per month.

        • Re: (Score:3, Insightful)

          by tomhudson ( 43916 )

          "I sell pet food and I'll say that Ol' Roy is one of the cheapest priced pet foods per bag. Sure there are some others cheaper per bag at feed stores which may or may not be a better deal. I know some feed stores that use loss leaders to beat Ol' Roy. But, when comparing Ol' Roy to premium pet food the price per feeding will beat Ol' Roy most every time. So, buying a $15 bag of feed per week is more expensive than buying a $26 bag of feed per month."

          It depends on which "Ol' Roy." If you buy the cheaper,

        • Although, WalMart is NOT a good example of profit optimization; there strategy is more likely to take cost decreases and pass them on. Which may not optimize the short term. And certainly only works if you are the more efficient retailer, which scale tends to help. But it is very pre-consumer and relatively dificult to compete against based upon price.

          A MUCH better example would be airlines; where what is practically the same product - a coach seat on the same flight might go for 5 to 8 price-points of $1
          • by no_pets ( 881013 )
            I disagree. Wal-Mart has similar and sometimes exactly the same product in slightly different packaging (size) so as not have to compete as aggressively as you might think. I actually worked at a Hypermart (one of the first Wal-Mart + grocery stores) in their bakery department. The local grocery stores had 7" and 9" pies. We had 8" pies. When the competitors advertised their pies as on sale customers would want us to match the prices. Wal-Mart will always match a competitor's advertised price on the exact s
            • Hmmm... I may want to examine this phenomenon if I can. Admittedly, a lot of the stuff I get at Wal*Mart isn't available at other local stores at all: either it's one of their store brands, or it's the only store in my area to routinely stock whatever item of whatever brand it is. (There's a difference.) But I might want to investigate differences in the items that I can get elsewhere.
              I thought their nutella came in a different size jar from everyone else's...
              I shop at a lot of stores that do this. W
    • by Mark_in_Brazil ( 537925 ) on Saturday April 28, 2007 @02:09PM (#18913303)

      Seriously - this is NOT new. Not even in the software field.

      First, a disclaimer. I was employee #4 at KhiMetrics, the company founded by Ken and Tim Ouimet (employees #1 and #2). They're mentioned in TFA. SAP bought KhiMetrics in January of 2006. Ken had been my office-mate in grad school. That said, I haven't seen Ken and Tim in years, and I have no financial stake in KhiMetrics or SAP anymore (SAP bought out the KhiMetrics stockholders with money, not shares of SAP stock).

      Yes, it's true that humans doing pricing try to do the same things. But the thing is that software can do things a human mind cannot. Yes, the opposite is also true, but here software has a lot of advantages. In the case of the KhiMetrics (now SAP) software, it works on the category level, optimizing profit for the category as a whole, which can include taking losses on individual items. The software never makes the common mistakes human beings make. For example, different "flavors" of the same size package of the same product should come out at the same price, and the unit price of a given item should go down as the amount bought increases. I can tell you that I have seen examples where humans have screwed this up this week. When there are two sizes of a given product, let's say a certain laundry detergent, then the price per weight of the larger package better be less than the price per weight of the smaller package, or there's never any incentive for the customer to buy the larger package. Still, I see examples where the pricers have gotten this wrong. I've even asked people at the stores if they were trying to move the smaller packages because of having too much of that size in stock or something, and they told me that no, they had no such problem.
      The other thing is that the KhiMetrics software uses actual sales data to determine how sensitive the customers are to the price of a given product. This can be done down to the SKU (individual item) level in the product dimension and down to the level of customers of a specific store in the geographic dimension. In other words, the KhiMetrics software is capable of determining the sensitivity of the customers of each individual store to the price of a specific product. No human being could do that at all, much less in the time the KhiMetrics software can do it. Even with a pricing team for each category in each store, which would end up costing a fortune in human resource costs, the result would not be as good as what KhiMetrics can deliver. Additionally, since the Ouimets "grew up in retail," the KhiMetrics software, since the beginning, has been compatible with things like Category Management and Efficient Replenishment, and able to take into account things like having different goals for different products in a category (loss leader, profit generator, traffic generator, etc.). The software takes into account complex factors like seasonality, promotion, and product visibility. Since I have a reasonably good idea of the internal workings of the software, I can tell you with some confidence that I, a Ph.D. in theoretical physics, would not even want to try to tackle the problem of optimizing the prices for a subcategory of 20 products in a single store, much less the dozens of categories and tens of thousands of SKUs in the dozens of stores in a retail chain. KhiMetrics can do all that, basing itself on years of actual sales data, before breakfast.

      There are experienced people in retail who are good at such things, but the software was created with people that have the same level of understanding of retail pricing, plus it has all the advantages of being able to do high-speed computerized analysis of huge amounts of price and sales data. I don't work for KhiMetrics anymore, nor for SAP, but I can say that if I were working in a retail company, I would definitely want us to be using software like this for pricing. And experienced retail people agree with me. One thing we saw back when I was with K

      • Re: (Score:3, Insightful)

        by tomhudson ( 43916 )

        "The software never makes the common mistakes human beings make. For example, different "flavors" of the same size package of the same product should come out at the same price, and the unit price of a given item should go down as the amount bought increases. I can tell you that I have seen examples where humans have screwed this up this week. When there are two sizes of a given product, let's say a certain laundry detergent, then the price per weight of the larger package better be less than the price per

        • Actually, this is quite common practice. A lot of people assume that just because the package is bigger, the "cost per gram" or "cost per ounce" MUST be lower - and they buy accordingly. Not only didn't the retailer screw up - he's making more by this "tax on ignorance."

          That's a good point. Also, as I mentioned in the grandparent post, sometimes a retailer might do that in order to move the smaller ones if they had too many units of that size in stock. But what's really cool is that the software can actu

          • The problem with that, of course, is going into a different store from the same chain and finding out that your usual store is ripping you off on certain items.

            This end up hurting "the brand", so franchisors won't do this at the store level, but at the chain level. Several chains tried doing this in the 60s by charging more to customers in the slums than in the suburbs, where there was more competition. Word of the practice got around, and people started voting with their feet - making the trek to the 'b

        • "and are willing to buy a years' worth at a time."

          "can afford to buy a year's worth at a time" perhaps. A years worth of mustard is great, unless all you get to eat all year is mustard. Like I should talk though; after spending maybe, oh, total 45$ this year for groceries total in the past two days I splurged and just spent 30$ on food(some of it was better than sex though, and I don't regret it, although I'm not going back for another meal there, ever, due to the cost).
      • Great post. I wonder though, how could this software (or similar) be used by a small business with fairly low sales volumes?

        As an example - my girlfriend is an optometrist with her own, single practise selling glasses, sunglasses and contact lenses. They don't sell anything in great volume and generally just make up prices as they go along.

        She would love to have software like this to give her some pricing guidance, but I personally don't see how it could work effectively without a lot of sales data to crunc
      • ... small volumes, e.g., form a specailty store, and also how does it handle Giffen Goods?

        What is the critical mass of sales data required to get good results? Has there been any effort or success in aggregating data from a number of small retailers to give them the results to match the information power of the larger retailers? Obviously, there would have to be secure handling of the data so the risk of letting out your sales data would be outweighed by the rewards of the improved pricing data.

        I'm also w
    • Well, if you ever walk into a university, you'll know that partial derivatives are beyond most business majors. So you can't expect them to try to find extrema points when multiple variables are involved. They need a "damn computer" to do it. This, of course, begs the question "is this really news?"
  • by kybred ( 795293 ) on Saturday April 28, 2007 @09:28AM (#18911545)
    and make it up in volume! That's what I always say.
    • Milo Minderbinder? Well I never! I always thought you were fictional!
    • Re: (Score:1, Interesting)

      by Anonymous Coward

      Sell at a loss...and make it up in volume!

      Actually that is a price optimization software I keep expecting to be put in use secretly by Walmart's competition. Walmart has "the guaranteed lowest prices every day", but only if you challenge them on it with an advertisement for lower price then they have listed. Most of the time when you do this they will match the lower price on same brand and often will on a store brand switch in for grocery store private labels advertised prices. Walmart's however does not i

  • by acvh ( 120205 ) <geek@msci[ ]s.com ['gar' in gap]> on Saturday April 28, 2007 @09:37AM (#18911591) Homepage
    this is more about consumer behavior than straight economics. the optimizations referred to aren't just adjusting pricing to supply and demand, but, as noted in the article, address perceived value as well. I'm no economist, nor do I want to be, but it seems to me that such analysis can uncover otherwise unexpected responses to price adjustments.
    • Re: (Score:2, Insightful)

      by Anonymous Coward
      This isn't just straight supply-and-demand like you get in a pretty, shiny free market. This is stuff like attempts at price discrimination in a market that's got monopolistic competition.

      Considering that pricing software can cost seven figures, what's going to come of all the money being spent on figuring out how to get us to spend our money?

      Interested parties will consider entering the market and driving down the cost, that's what. Or maybe consider selling different versions (more price discrimination)

    • by ACNeal ( 595975 )
      Although this isn't as obvious as most people will immediately think it is, it is worth a "duh".

      The is basically "Cost Accounting". As the first poster pointed out, this has been done for centuries. Using computer models will make it better and/or faster, but that is the same reason we use computers for just about any computationally boring process.
    • this is more about consumer behavior than straight economics. the optimizations referred to aren't just adjusting pricing to supply and demand, but, as noted in the article, address perceived value as well. I'm no economist, nor do I want to be, but it seems to me that such analysis can uncover otherwise unexpected responses to price adjustments.

      Exactly, though I'd argue that even straight economics has a large behavioral component. What this does is let organizations maximize profits by tuning price to de
    • by hamelis ( 820185 )
      Let's remember that supply and demand are curves, and that any intersection is only for a given price/quantity combination. At a lower price, more people would buy, but whether the supplier would have higher or lower revenue/profit is ambiguous. With effective use of price discrimination, suppliers can capture more surplus.

      To expand the LCD TV example used above, let's say the original, static price was $700 (with a cost of $500). Before price discrimination, they make one sale to Mr. MBA and receive $20
    • by fermion ( 181285 )
      To use a favorite reason that command economies do not work, economics theories are difficult because people are not bacteria. Optimizing price for "consumer behavior" is nontrivial at best, and maybe intractable. This is why setting prices using a competitive environment, while not ideal, does often work.

      Typically, people only have a limited tolerance for "perceived value", especially on commodities. One might occasionally go to the corner market and pay 50% more an equivalent product, but if people h

  • by G4from128k ( 686170 ) on Saturday April 28, 2007 @09:39AM (#18911599)
    Customers vary in their willingness and ability to pay. If a company charges one simple price for each item, it creates a situation in which some people get a great deal (they pay less than they might be willing to) and some people don't buy the product at all (because the price is more than they want to pay). But if a company can find a way to separate the customers that really value the product from the customers that value it less, then more people will be able to buy the product and the company will earn more profit. (You mathematically prove that this increases what is called consumer surplus which is the equivalent to the consumers "profit" on the purchase and the seller's profit). Both side benefit, as does society.

    The amusing fact is that this is nothing more than a capitalist version of taking from the rich (those are willing and able to pay more) and giving to the poor (those aren't willing or able to pay more).
    • by Anonymous Coward on Saturday April 28, 2007 @09:44AM (#18911635)
      Yes, this is true, but you don't need complicated mathematical schemes for this. They've been doing it for years.

      It's called coupons!

      The product is priced on the shelf at the price most consumers are willing to pay (say, about 60%). The coupon discounts the product to a price the other 40% are willing to pay. Now you get to charge two prices for the same product! Woohoo!
      • by aethera ( 248722 )
        That's not the only way they get you. Ever notice how the store brand products invariably have much brighter and, lets face it, much uglier color schemes on the packaging. Its not because the margins are so thin on those generic brands that they can't afford to design better packaging. Stores want anyone who is able to afford (or thinks they deserve to be able to afford) the more expensive name brands to be sunconsciously turned off by the garish packinging, and maybe a little embaressed to be seen with it
        • Re: (Score:2, Interesting)

          by impos ( 805511 )
          well I'm not going to comment on the quality of store brands, but in my 20+ years at Kroger, I know the store brands make a boatload of profit compared to the national brands... like a 4-1 margin... on some items, mayonaise for example, we'd make 60 to 70 cents on the store brand per unit, maybe 10-15 cents on Kraft or Best Foods. And that's only one example out of about 8000 or so.

          We aggressively pushed store brands, the profits were much greater.
    • by Nf1nk ( 443791 ) <nf1nk@@@yahoo...com> on Saturday April 28, 2007 @10:02AM (#18911717) Homepage
      One technique for this is the extended warranty racket. For the perception of improved service, and to make up for frequent shoddy workmanship, the product is available with several different layers of warranty available. The person who can marginally afford the product gets just the product but no added service or peace of mind, the person who will pay more for the product, gets the service he should expect with a quality piece of merchandise. All with just one line of product.
      • Re: (Score:2, Informative)

        by slk ( 2510 )
        In your description of the extended warranty racket, you have just describe Apple's business model. You buy something expensive and of marginal quality (sorry, apple's hardware build quality is awful, though OSX is really nice) and then you have the big upsell to Applecare (takes care of everything for 3 years).
    • Re: (Score:2, Insightful)

      No to be rude - and you're correct in your premise - but that is typically called (market) segmentation in the industry, and not price optimization (I have some background in telecom marketing segmentation). The idea that one can segment their customer base and target product marketing efforts (either by price, features, or what advertising is focused on) is a little different than the article, which talks about looking at behavior within a larger set (the entire "chain") are large demographic subset (all
      • Not only that, but the consumer surplus does not increase with prize differentiation. Just the contrary. The gained profit comes from the previous consumer surplus. With perfect prize diffentiation, the consumer surplus is zero.
      • by G4from128k ( 686170 ) on Saturday April 28, 2007 @11:03AM (#18912049)
        Yes, you are right that they are separate but related. (Your post is not rude and I hope my response is not rude, either). The lead example concerned pricing of drills. The three models (perhaps from three different makers) define different market segments as far as the retailer is concerned. Optimizing the price on the three models gives the retailer a chance to maximize both revenues and profits even if the retailer doesn't do anything to market the products differently. Similarly, markdown optimization is both a price optimization and a segmentation issue -- segmenting the "I'll pay anything to be the first person to own this" customers from the "I'll buy it later when its discounted" customers.

        The classic example, that I was thinking of, is the revenue management strategies of airlines that attempt to optimize prices across presumed underlying segments of price-sensitive leisure travelers versus price-insensitive business travelers. Technically, it's the identical seat that's being sold for radically different prices (up to 10X different) depending on issues such as how the customer buys the ticket, when they buy the ticket, whether they book a saturday-night stay, etc. The result is that the business customers pay for the plane and the vacation travelers only pay for the fuel and variable costs. The ability to differentiate does benefit the business customers because the added volume of travelers means a more frequent schedule of flights, larger planes, and more destinations.

        You are right, though, that true market segmentation involves much more than just price optimization.
    • by bitt3n ( 941736 ) on Saturday April 28, 2007 @10:19AM (#18911823)

      The amusing fact is that this is nothing more than a capitalist version of taking from the rich (those are willing and able to pay more) and giving to the poor (those aren't willing or able to pay more).
      Except it isn't necessarily the case that the rich are willing to pay more. It's the people who think they're rich, or want to look like they are.
      • by arose ( 644256 )
        Besides it's not giving to the poor, it's taking as much as you can take from everyone.
    • by dubl-u ( 51156 ) * <<ot.atop> <ta> <2107893252>> on Saturday April 28, 2007 @10:23AM (#18911849)
      The amusing fact is that this is nothing more than a capitalist version of taking from the rich (those are willing and able to pay more) and giving to the poor (those aren't willing or able to pay more).

      Some people might think you are kidding there, but there really are cases where everybody wins from differential pricing, and businesses really do take from the rich so they can afford to sell to the poor. Let me add an example to make it clearer:

      Imagine you want to build some sort of clever new software. You see that 10,000 people would pay $100 for it (as a fun toy, say), and 5 companies would pay $1m for it, because they can each make $3m from using it commercially.

      If the software costs $1m to develop and you sell all the copies for $100, your profit will be $500. Nobody's going to go to all that trouble for $500, so you wouldn't make the software. And if you did, you'd be steamed that these companies made millions while you got pocket lint.

      However, if you sell the first 5 copies for $1m each (with, say, some fancy documentation and a support contract), you can then go on to release a consumer version to get everybody else. You get $5m in the bank, so you're happy. The companies netted $10m, so they're happy. And everybody else got a fun toy at a reasonable price.

      Note that although your average price per copy there is $600, you couldn't get the same effect by charging $600; none of the consumers would pay that much for a toy.
      • by bit01 ( 644603 )

        Your reasoning only applies to a non-free market.

        In a truly free market the people who bought the software for $100 would be able to on-sell it to the business for $110, meaning the original vendor would be out of a sale.

        The fancy documentation and support contract is a different product that some companies are willing to pay more for. It's also bundling. It's not differential pricing on the same product.

        I'd like to see both differential pricing and all on-selling restrictions made illegal. This would

        • I'd like to see both differential pricing and all on-selling restrictions made illegal. This would promote a more free, fair and optimal market. Not simple to implement though.

          How would that be more optimal? The result would be that the hypothetical company sells the software for $1 million only, and the 10,000 other potential customers never get to see it.
    • ... would it work in practice? Wouldn't tap into good ol' fashioned human greed, and force those penny-pinching rich folk out there to only accept "poor" rates? Wouldn't the egalitarians cry murder as the poor are elevated above the rich? It seems nice, but giving to the poor, taking from the rich, it isn't what capitalism is for.
    • The amusing fact is that this is nothing more than a capitalist version of taking from the rich (those are willing and able to pay more) and giving to the poor (those aren't willing or able to pay more).

      No, it's getting the maximum amount of money from each customer. They're not giving anybody anything - they're charging the rich more.

      As a side benefit, it can make a product more profitable and promote more development, so I guess the poor benefit from that... Kinda like people who buy version 1 of $NewStuff. (As a Version 3+ guy, thanks!)

    • Not quite.
      One example was a store that had a line of paintbrushes and was selling too many of the cheapest paintbrushes. Solution for store? Discontinue the cheapest paintbrush, since the customers tend to buy the paintbrushes at the same time as the paint and therefore won't shop around.
      This benefits no one but the store.
      • '' One example was a store that had a line of paintbrushes and was selling too many of the cheapest paintbrushes. Solution for store? Discontinue the cheapest paintbrush, since the customers tend to buy the paintbrushes at the same time as the paint and therefore won't shop around.
        This benefits no one but the store. ''

        The problem is that customers are not stupid, and eventually they realise that there is likely a reason why you can't get cheap paintbrushes at this store. So either they just realise that thi
    • by bit01 ( 644603 )

      (You mathematically prove that this increases what is called consumer surplus which is the equivalent to the consumers "profit" on the purchase and the seller's profit)

      This cannot be true. Take it to the limit, where the vendor can set a different price for every customer. If it's a monopoly they set the price to a tiny fraction less than whatever it's worth to the customer and all customer surplus is close to zero. If it's a competitive market with no price fixing going on then they must set the price

  • game the system (Score:4, Interesting)

    by Anonymous Coward on Saturday April 28, 2007 @09:46AM (#18911649)
    As other posters will doubtless already have said, price point optimisation by software is neither new nor interesting. What is interesting IMHO is the scale of the whole system. Big box superstores employ an army of psychologists, ergonomics experts and statisticians to try and control your behaviour and squeeze as much cash as possible from your pocket.

    There was a quite fascinating article published the other day in a Digg linked blog that I am sure many here read (I don't have the link unfortunately). What is really interesting is that by knowing the system and subverting it you can make HUGE savings in your shopping. The layout of the store is carefully crafted to expose you to the products they want to push. Color schemes and shelf placememt are designed to confuse or lead you to select certain products. Prices and product sizes are carefully designed to make comparative math very difficult to ordinary folks. Bargains are placed outside the normal lines of sight.

    In other words, the very existence of a cold and calculated system is what enables you to game it.

    Some bits of strategy I remember:

    1) Make a list and stick to it. Impulse purchases account for a huge amount of profit and the stores rely on you buying things you do not need.
    2) Never look at the products at eye level, they are the most expensive and worst value.
    3) Move as fast as you can to the back of the store. Start at the back of the store and work your way forwards.
    4) Do not stop unncecessarily. Deliberate impedences are put in isles to slow you down.
    5) Don't take a cart or basket unless you really can't carry what is written on your list.
    6) Use the bathroom before you go shopping. They place the restrooms to make you walk as far as possible past tempting impulse products.

    A couple of my own...

    7) Eat before you shop, never go to a grocery supermarket when hungry.
    8) Take cash, just as much as you need and no more, and use the cash only fast checkout.

    Perhaps someone who knows the systems they use in detail should write a piece of open source software in their spare time to calculate the optimal path through a store :)
    • Re:game the system (Score:5, Insightful)

      by stoolpigeon ( 454276 ) <bittercode@gmail> on Saturday April 28, 2007 @10:20AM (#18911835) Homepage Journal
      2) Never look at the products at eye level, they are the most expensive and worst value.
       
      That is really not a valid statement, for a couple reasons. The first error is the last two words 'worst value'. Only the customer can determine what the value is. If I'm looking at a condiment section and at eye level is a name brand catsup, and below it is a private label equivalent, the price per unit will probably be lower on the private label. That doesn't necessarily make it a better value. If I think the private label tastes rotten and wont eat it, the more expensive catsup is a much better value.
       
      The second issue is that quite often what you see at eye level is determined by who payed for the placement. It may not be the highest margin item for the retailer on its own. But it is their because the vendor payed a royalty to have it where they want it.
       
        3) Move as fast as you can to the back of the store. Start at the back of the store and work your way forwards.
       
      That doesn't make a whole lot of sense. If you are talking grocery, very few stores are laid out the same way. There's no way this can be a 'rule' that will help you when what is at the front or back will vary from location to location. I think a better way of looking at this might be - don't buy what is on end-caps and floor displays until you have looked at the prices for comparable items. This means, not running to the back, but going to the aisle where the item is normally located.
       
      In larger stores this really doesn't make sense. If I go to Fry's Electronics and run to the back, how does that help me? If I go to Best Buy and hustle right back to home appliances, I'm not sure what I've done to help myself out.
       
      The psychology of all this is over rated. A little common sense - like many of the other suggestions in the list, will go a long way. That's not manipulating the 'system' it's just using your mind and operating above a visceral level.
    • I have a better way to game the system: don't participate in "the system". Shop at your friendly local, independent retailers. In our store, we put things where people can find them, and price them competitively.
      • Good idea, but it only works if many people have that idea. One metro area I'm familiar with has very few local independent grocery stores, and almost no general-purpose ones. It wasn't always that way: it took a couple of decades. As more people entered the system, fewer people could keep the local stores going. The stores just closed one by one.
        Of course, that metro area has several related local grocery chains. Do they count?
    • BEFORE you even make a list, define a meal plan for each meal of the day and only buy enough to cover those meals. This will save you significant amounts of money as you won't be raiding the fridge to come up with dinner. I easily halved my food costs in this manner, but the downside is you eat a lot of the same meals, like spaghetti, so it can get monotonous.

      A lot of stores, such as Safeway for example, include the unit price on their shelf tags. This is very convenient when comparing the cost among brands
      • by DogDude ( 805747 )
        As an adult should be able to walk down the cereal aisle without having to put your hands over your eyes to resist buying the Fruity Pebbles. Just stick to your damn list like a big boy or girl.

        You clearly have never been to the grocery store while high.
      • Hey, as an adult I bought Corn Pops yesterday while shopping. They were on sale and I realized I hadn't had them in years. Being an adult means you can eat like a kid once in a while.
    • Prices and product sizes are carefully designed to make comparative math very difficult to ordinary folks.

      Luckily, all the grocery stores that I frequent have the price/oz printed on the price cards on the shelf edges. I wonder why they'd do that if they want to make it hard for shoppers to compare? Could it be that the advantage of making customers more willing to shop at their store (vs. a competitor) outweighs the disadvantage of being less able to sneak in poor deals? Or do, perhaps, the lower priced s

    • by Anonymous Coward
      Hah. The parent basically quoted the main points of an article that hit the front page of digg the other day: 15 ways stores trick you into spending [msn.com].
    • 8) Take cash, just as much as you need and no more, and use the cash only fast checkout.
      Oddly the best buys around here have 1 cash line which is almost always slwoer then the 3 credit/debit lines. they know your strategies and are attempting to defeat you!
      • Oddly the best buys around here have 1 cash line which is almost always slwoer then the 3 credit/debit lines. they know your strategies and are attempting to defeat you!

        That's not my experience. Even if it was, I'm willing to jump to the credit lines if the line is too long anyway. If they want to pay that extra ~3% fee to take a charge after I've already made my purchase choices whereas taking cash with a couple anti-counterfeit measures costs a lot less, then that's their prerogative.
        • Surely Best Buy doesn't force you to use credit in the credit line?
          Most grocery stores have express lanes for n items or less. Sometimes they're faster, sometimes they're slower (no conveyer belt & too many people with less than n items), and these days they're often self-serve. But nobody has ever stopped me from using a normal aisle for less than n items, even when the express lane is open.

    • 2) Never look at the products at eye level, they are the most expensive and worst value.


      If that were the case, shouldn't candy, cookies, ice cream, and action figures be spread out over the entire store on shelves about 2-3 feet from the ground?

      • I think he meant the worst value for that class of food.
        The candy is in two sections, the checkouts and an in-store shelf; the checkout candy will usually be a "worse value" than the in-store candy, and the candy that's easily visible will be a "worse value" than the candy that's buried in the skinny shelves below eye level.
        Cookies have their own section for the most part, but the "worst values" will be at eye level. Below eye-level, there are no cookies--only crackers.
        Ice cream will have its own sectio
  • Maybe the author has not yet discovered "Why We Buy".

    A cruise thru "The Power of Persuasion" by Robert Levine
    might also be enlightning.
  • by LaughingCoder ( 914424 ) on Saturday April 28, 2007 @09:49AM (#18911667)
    I wonder how much this software costs. Does everyone pay the same price for it?
  • So what is new? (Score:3, Informative)

    by figleaf ( 672550 ) on Saturday April 28, 2007 @10:21AM (#18911839) Homepage
    Lots of companies have been using it for a long time.

    I have used a prize optimization solutions based of MS SQL Server back in 2005
    http://www.microsoft.com/industry/retail/solutions /priceoptimization.mspx [microsoft.com]
  • by argoff ( 142580 ) * on Saturday April 28, 2007 @10:51AM (#18911973)
    You see. A lot of stores would like to charge each and every customer a different price. Those prices being the set that maximizes revenues from that particular customer. But in practice that is very difficult. Changing differnet prices on the same item for every sale would be cumbersome, and customers who see the person in front of them get a better deal than they do might get pissed. The stores response to this is customer "value" cards.

    In an idea scenario, they set all prices on the high end - but then give the customers "value" cards that offer varing discounts and rewards so as to optimize sales and profit. For example, if they know you won't pay more than $2 for a soda, then your soda will always be $2. For example, they might do something like use buying habits track your period. If you buy tampons on the day of your period - you will get reamed hard because they know you need them right now, but if you buy them in the off cycle then you get a good deal. If you buy just milk in the early morning, you will get reamed hard because they know you might need it for breakfast right then, but if you buy it later on you will get a competitive discount. If you buy a phone today, but the last phone you bought was two years ago and had a two year average lifespan, then you get reamed hard because they know you need a replacement right now. Otherwise you get a deal. If you buy condoms on friday night, you get a nailed hard, but if you buy them on wednesday morning you get a great deal.

    • Re: (Score:1, Insightful)

      by Anonymous Coward
      Thats not how the cards work. There are two price tiers: one for non card holders and one for those with cards.

      In fact, the scenario you described with the cards is exactly the same one you said customers wouldn't tolerate. It is also illegal in many places.
    • by wkitchen ( 581276 ) on Saturday April 28, 2007 @11:25AM (#18912219)
      And how is that going to affect buying decisions when the buyer doesn't know about it until checkout time?

      If the gallon of milk is marked $4.99 on the shelf, the customer who is unwilling to pay more than $3 is not going to put it in his cart. That the store plans to discount it to $2.99 at the register won't change that. And if the customer is willing to pick up the $4.99 milk, what incentive is there for the store to charge less for it?
      • Some of the stores I go to have value cards. Here's how they handle it:
        When there is a lower price for people with value cards and a higher price for people without them, the store covers the area on the shelf listing the normal higher price with a large card giving the lower price (for people with value cards) in huge numbers.
        People with value cards know what they'll pay immediately and will be attracted to the sale items.
        People without value cards can look under the big card to find the real price.
        Pe
    • "...If you buy condoms on friday night, you get a nailed hard, but if you buy them on wednesday morning you get a great deal."

      Sounds like you're getting a great deal either way!
    • ... If you buy condoms on friday night, you get a nailed hard, ...

      I'd say it's my girlfriend who get's nailed hard.

      *DaaDum Crash! Thud.*
  • you'd learn how to do price optimization yourself. This is nothing new - anyone with the right data and training can do this; the product simply makes it easier. Thank you for the astroturfing.
    • Re: (Score:2, Insightful)

      by c_sd_m ( 995261 )
      It's not just price optimization that's relatively easy to learn. There's also location theory and optimization (e.g., retail, essential and emergency services, noxious facilities), routing and scheduling, order and inventory levels, ... The math is relatively simple (most of the time) and if you can set up the problems there are some decent OS software packages with very good solvers. COIN-OR comes to mind but I'm sure there are several.
      The real issues are getting the data and interpreting the results
  • Why not save the cost of using software to calculate prices, and just ask the stockholders what they'd like to see it priced at? After all, ultimately they are the ones in control of the company. You might as well let them set the pricing so when profits drop, you can tell them "You wanted it, we did it. We're not to blame" and if profits soar then the stockholders can be pleased with their decision.
    • by shmlco ( 594907 )
      Yeah, let's have a stockholders meeting for WalMart. We can sit down and determine the price for each one of the 142,000 items a SuperCenter stocks.
      • by Khyber ( 864651 )
        Yup, it's just as simple as a meeting going "How much should we markup our items?" I could see a company just doing a flat rate price hike to get their profit and not worrying about individual pricing.
        • A store that just used flat mark-ups might not do as well as one with higher mark-ups in general but lower mark-ups, or even mark-downs, on popular staples. People would go to the store which had mark-downs for the stuff that was marked down, but likely would buy some expensive stuff there as well.
          Surely a store that prominently advertises "Rollbacks" is not using a flat price mark-up!
        • by shmlco ( 594907 )
          If you'd have RTFA you would have seen that they covered this point pretty well. But if you want to do it on a per-category basis that will cut our meeting a lot shorter, as WM only stocks about 40,000 different types of items.
  • by spywhere ( 824072 ) on Saturday April 28, 2007 @12:37PM (#18912657)
    I was the purchasing agent for a chain of auto parts stores, and we used a method called GROI: Gross Return on Inventory.
    The original pricing theory in traditional auto parts stores was based on four "turns" per year: after opening a parts store and filling it up with stuff to sell, you needed to sell each stock number four times, at 35% gross profit, to make an adequate gross profit to cover your expenses -- and pay off your inventory in twelve months.
    This resulted in some items being priced much higher than at mass retailers, and caused stores to lose sales on popular items: people would go elsewhere for oil, antifreeze, and the most common spark plugs, brake pads and filters, because they were much less expensive at places like Pep Boys.
    The GROI method constantly recalculated sales and adjusted the prices downward on popular items, thus increasing sales and lowering the prices still further. For example, the best-selling oil filters would sell at under 10% gross profit, but we would sell out our inventory of those items twelve to fifteen times per year... thus making a larger profit on the initial purchases we had made to stock a new store. By setting a minimum gross profit percentage, runaway sales on an item would result in higher profits instead of ever-lower margins.

    This was all calculated by an incredibly expensive 200 MHz Pentium Pro box, running proprietary software atop SCO Unix.
    (I was the only one who could work the thing... which led to me running a newly purchased Netware 4.1 network in the chain's offices... which led me out of that filthy auto parts business altogether, thank Jeebus).
  • Wonder if amazon charges a higher price on your first click, then if you don't buy and return several months later, they lower the price based on your contemplation time.

  • I interviewed with a local supermarket mega-chain a couple years ago for a project doing exactly this. Compare prices at each store against what other stores are charging, and model the impact of tweaking the price of a can of Campbell's Tomato Soup by a cent or two (for example).

    Airlines have been doing this for years. And hotels, and other industries. Apartment complex management is getting into the game as well.

    I have a friend who works for a rental car company, he does this sort of thing in his head at
  • Price optimization will happen in a free market, whether by Intelligent Design or the evolutionary optimization referred to by Adam Smith as the "invisible hand."

    Of course, if you're a company selling stuff, evolution favors the intelligently designed.
  • I remember when Target actually had useful stuff instead of being a big 7-11 with clothing. In recent years, we've been visiting the neighborhood hardware and auto stores again like we didn't for years. Imagine being happy to pay 30 cent/piece for screws because, dammit, I'll know they have them.

    I mention Target because they give me the creeps. I leave with the feeling that I'm never really getting a deal and every item of inventory and model of that item has been efficiently spreadsheeted for optimum pr
  • TFA is to an AP news story but displayed on iWon. Is this not the same iWon that keeps spamming me all the time????
    Who the hell are these people?

Time is the most valuable thing a man can spend. -- Theophrastus

Working...